QuestionsAnswered.net
What's Your Question?

How to Write a Research Paper
Writing a research paper is a bit more difficult that a standard high school essay. You need to site sources, use academic data and show scientific examples. Before beginning, you’ll need guidelines for how to write a research paper.
Start the Research Process
Before you begin writing the research paper, you must do your research. It is important that you understand the subject matter, formulate the ideas of your paper, create your thesis statement and learn how to speak about your given topic in an authoritative manner. You’ll be looking through online databases, encyclopedias, almanacs, periodicals, books, newspapers, government publications, reports, guides and scholarly resources. Take notes as you discover new information about your given topic. Also keep track of the references you use so you can build your bibliography later and cite your resources.
Develop Your Thesis Statement
When organizing your research paper, the thesis statement is where you explain to your readers what they can expect, present your claims, answer any questions that you were asked or explain your interpretation of the subject matter you’re researching. Therefore, the thesis statement must be strong and easy to understand. Your thesis statement must also be precise. It should answer the question you were assigned, and there should be an opportunity for your position to be opposed or disputed. The body of your manuscript should support your thesis, and it should be more than a generic fact.
Create an Outline
Many professors require outlines during the research paper writing process. You’ll find that they want outlines set up with a title page, abstract, introduction, research paper body and reference section. The title page is typically made up of the student’s name, the name of the college, the name of the class and the date of the paper. The abstract is a summary of the paper. An introduction typically consists of one or two pages and comments on the subject matter of the research paper. In the body of the research paper, you’ll be breaking it down into materials and methods, results and discussions. Your references are in your bibliography. Use a research paper example to help you with your outline if necessary.
Organize Your Notes
When writing your first draft, you’re going to have to work on organizing your notes first. During this process, you’ll be deciding which references you’ll be putting in your bibliography and which will work best as in-text citations. You’ll be working on this more as you develop your working drafts and look at more white paper examples to help guide you through the process.
Write Your Final Draft
After you’ve written a first and second draft and received corrections from your professor, it’s time to write your final copy. By now, you should have seen an example of a research paper layout and know how to put your paper together. You’ll have your title page, abstract, introduction, thesis statement, in-text citations, footnotes and bibliography complete. Be sure to check with your professor to ensure if you’re writing in APA style, or if you’re using another style guide.
MORE FROM QUESTIONSANSWERED.NET

Follow World Bank Publications on Facebook , Twitter or Linked-In

- Español - Beta
- Français - Beta
Browse this collection
Author profiles, site statistics.
- Collections
- Sub-Saharan Africa Sustainable Development Goals
- » 08. Working Papers
- » Policy Research Working Papers
Greed and Grievance in Civil War

Show full item record
Collection(s)
This item appears in the following collection(s).
- Policy Research Working Papers
Show Statistical Information
Related items
Showing items related by title, author, creator and subject.

Military Expenditure : Threats, Aid, and Arms Races

On the Duration of Civil War

Understanding Civil War : Evidence and Analysis, Volume 2. Europe, Central Asia, and Other Regions
Browse Econ Literature
- Working papers
- Software components
- Book chapters
- JEL classification
More features
- Subscribe to new research
RePEc Biblio
Author registration.
- Economics Virtual Seminar Calendar NEW!

Greed and grievance in civil war
- Author & abstract
- Download & other version
- 19 References
- 1007 Citations
- Most related
- Related works & more
Corrections
- Collier, Paul
- Hoeffler, Anke
- Paul Collier
- Anke Hoeffler
Suggested Citation
Download full text from publisher, other versions of this item:, references listed on ideas.
Follow serials, authors, keywords & more
New papers by email
Subscribe to new additions to RePEc
Public profiles for Economics researchers
Various research rankings in Economics

RePEc Genealogy
Who was a student of whom, using RePEc
Curated articles & papers on economics topics
Upload your paper to be listed on RePEc and IDEAS
EconAcademics
Blog aggregator for economics research
Cases of plagiarism in Economics
Job market papers
RePEc working paper series dedicated to the job market
Fantasy league
Pretend you are at the helm of an economics department
Services from the StL Fed
Data, research, apps & more from the St. Louis Fed
About RePEc
Initiative for open bibliographies in Economics
News about RePEc
Questions about IDEAS and RePEc
RePEc volunteers
Participating archives
Publishers indexing in RePEc
Privacy statement
Legal statement.
Found an error or omission?
Opportunities to help RePEc
Get papers listed
Have your research listed on RePEc
Open a RePEc archive
Have your institution's/publisher's output listed on RePEc
Get RePEc data
Use data assembled by RePEc
The Journal of Conflict Resolution is an interdisciplinary journal of social scientific research and theory on human conflict. The journal focuses largely on international conflict, but also explores a variety of national, intergroup and interpersonal conflicts.
Sara Miller McCune founded SAGE Publishing in 1965 to support the dissemination of usable knowledge and educate a global community. SAGE is a leading international provider of innovative, high-quality content publishing more than 900 journals and over 800 new books each year, spanning a wide range of subject areas. A growing selection of library products includes archives, data, case studies and video. SAGE remains majority owned by our founder and after her lifetime will become owned by a charitable trust that secures the company’s continued independence. Principal offices are located in Los Angeles, London, New Delhi, Singapore, Washington DC and Melbourne. www.sagepublishing.com
This item is part of a JSTOR Collection. For terms and use, please refer to our Terms and Conditions The Journal of Conflict Resolution Request Permissions
‘Greed’ and ‘Grievance’ as Motivations for Civil War: The Libyan Case
Introduction
The last decade has been characterised by a lively debate about “greed” and “grievance” as causes of civil wars. Before, arguments about the outbreak of civil wars focused on the irrationality and ‘essentially inexplicably primordial qualities’ of human beings (Pugh and Cooper, 2003 in Berdal, 2005, p. 688). However, at the start of the 21 st century Collier and Hoeffler (2000) argued that their statistical data pointed towards economic incentives as being the main cause of the outbreak of violent rebellion.
There was wide-spread criticism of Collier and Hoeffler’s work. One such criticism focused on the fact that it is impossible to impose the type of generalisation of civil wars that they attempted in their work. Civil wars are caused by highly complex social processes that greatly depend on the historical and regional context. Therefore, it is important to study the causes of civil wars in the context of the specific case. In short, it is necessary to move from generalised statistics to case studies (Cramer, 2002; Nathan, 2005, p.11).
The Arab Spring provides new opportunities for the study of civil wars. The wave of protests has led to two violent rebellions: the Libyan revolutionary war and the Syrian civil war. Both are new case studies for the outbreak of violent rebellion and can therefore provide new insights into causes and motivations for civil war and the validity of greed and grievance factors as motivations. In order to do justice to the case, this paper will discuss whether the distinction between greed and grievance is useful to explain the outbreak of civil war in Libya.
Firstly, I determine the arrest of Fathi Terbil as the trigger event that marks the start of civil war. Then I consider the greed thesis and I conclude that the situation in Libya does not conform to the conditions for greed-based rebellion as put forward in Collier and Hoeffler’s original work. Nevertheless, there is a lack of research into the motivations of rebels to completely rule out that they were motivated by the prospect of oil income. In regards to grievances, several can be identified. Both vertical inequalities: economic grievances, a lack of political rights, and the lifestyle of the Gadaffi children, as well as horizontal inequalities: regional as well as tribal differences. This collection of grievances seems to have been the main motivation for Libyans to choose violent rebellion. However, most of these grievances have been present for at least a decade. We need to look at the ‘rebel’s dilemma’ and the role that government decisions played in allowing its own demise. When studying the outbreak of civil war, the distinction between grievances and opportunity might turn out to be more helpful.
The Start of the Libyan Civil War
In their original paper, Collier and Hoeffler use a number of 1.000 deaths per year as the baseline for ‘civil war’ (2000, p.4). However, other scholars argue that this is too rigid a distinction and that some conflicts with fewer casualties do share the characteristics of civil war (Nathan, 2005, p.15). This definition risks defining civil wars too late, or too early, and might define a peace when conflict is still ongoing. To overcome this, the ‘contested sovereignty situation’ definition can be used (Florea, 2012, p.87). This describes a situation in which different groups claim jurisdictions in (parts of) the territory. In Libya, the start of violent protests can be pinpointed on the arrest of Fathi Terbil. Protests for his release led to a brutal response by the regime and a ‘spiral of violence’ in the east (Pargeter, 2012, p.221). By the end of the month most of the east was out of Gadaffi’s control (ibid, p.223). By this time, the conflict can be described as a situation of contested sovereignty and thus as a civil war. The next two sections will focus on two explanations for the outbreak of civil war: greed-based and grievance-based motivations.
Greed-Based Explanations
In accordance with other revolutions during the Arab Spring, the Libyan rebel movement focused its narrative on demands for democratic reforms. However, Collier and Hoeffler (2000) argue that all rebellions are accompanied by a narrative of grievance, simply because publicly announcing greed-based motivations would lead to reduced support. As a consequence, their main explanation for the outbreak of conflict is greed: rebels are interested in the profits that they can make from predation upon primary commodities. Collier and Hoeffler argue that the main characteristics of civil war-prone states are: heavy reliance on primary commodity exports, a large percentage of unemployed and uneducated young men, and a sudden and rapid economic decline. Does the Libyan case conform to their definition? It does in part: the country strongly relies on primary commodity exports in the form of oil, and it had an estimated unemployment rate of 30% in 2004. However, up to 2011 the economic growth rate had been relatively stable and education indicators in Libya were relatively positive, with high literacy rates and more years of schooling than other states in the region (CIA, 2012 and Kabbani, 2005). Therefore it is questionable whether we could categorise Libya in the way that Collier and Hoeffler intended.
Additionally, their argument assumes that in states with those characteristics, the opportunity costs of rebellion are low and that citizens are thus likely to attempt to use it to capture the income from primary commodities. However, proxies of a potential for greed can often be used also as proxies for grievances, as exemplified by low schooling in Sierra Leone, which can both be a source of social anger and a reason for low opportunity costs for rebellion (Cramer, 2002, p.1853). With regard to Libya the interpretation could also be two-fold: either there were indeed rebels who saw an economic opportunity in taking control of the oil reserves in Libya, or the lack of distribution of income from oil should be regarded as a grievance that became part of a more general discontent with the policies of the Gadaffi regime.
Furthermore, the behaviour of rebels in the initial phase of the rebellion does not seem to confirm the greed thesis, as there were no reports of significant looting. Nevertheless, the role of oil would merit more study, as the rebels moved to control this resource fairly quickly and it would need to be confirmed that they limited themselves to controlling resources necessary for the war (England and Blas, 2011). As mentioned above, rebel movements have an incentive to portray to the outside world that grievances are their main motivation. As a result, without research that engages directly with their personal motivations it is impossible to determine whether quick profit from oil resources was a major motivation for the rebels. In short, while there were no signs of self-enrichment as a motivation for the rebels, it cannot be disproven that the prospect of riches was a reason for violence.
Another case in which greed-based motivations can come to play a more important role is when the conflict drags on for a long time. Economic interests develop for groups that want to take advantage of the conflict (Keen, 2000, p.27). Evidence for this in Libya is provided by Dirk Vandewalle (2012b) in an interview with Foreign Affairs on ‘rogue militias’ which developed in Libya during the war and that still attempt to profit from violence after the overthrow of Gadaffi. The role of oil can possibly be seen in this light: apart from being a lifeline for the rebel movement, revolutionaries could quickly get an incentive for, or established interest in, control over oil.
Grievances in Libya
In contrast to the greed-thesis as proposed by Collier and Hoeffler, many scholars still argue that the historic record shows grievances as an important motivation for violent rebellion. Frances Stewart (2002) distinguishes between two types of inequalities: vertical and horizontal. The former refers to inequalities as measured on a societal level between individuals, while the latter measures inequalities between social groups, where one social group is marginalised compared to others. Stewart further argues that both vertical and horizontal inequalities can be motivations for civil war, with horizontal inequalities at least equally likely a cause of conflict, because ‘[where they] coincide with economic and political differences between groups, this can cause deep resentment that may lead to violent struggles’ (Stewart and Brown in Stewart, 2010, p.2). When studying the case of Libya, vertical grievances can be found in terms of the economic position of the population, the lack of political rights and the behaviour of Gadaffi’s family. Additionally, horizontal grievances exist between regions and between tribes.
Firstly, the Libyan society has suffered under the economic policies of the regime. In the 1990s, international sanctions were imposed on Libya that mainly hit the poorer citizens. To make matters worse, the sanctions regime was abused by the rich class, who managed to sell off food allowances and gained unique access to foreign products. In the meantime, public services were eroded (Pargenter, 2012, pp.172-3). As a result, the gap between the rich and poor in Libya widened. In 2003 this worsened, as subsidies were removed, thereby further angering Libyans (ibid, p.194-5). The combination of poor employment opportunities and the fact that education levels strongly increased in recent decades can be seen as a major source of vertical economic grievance, as it was impossible for citizens to work on the level that they were trained for (Campante and Chor, 2012).
Secondly, political power was uniformly in the hands of the regime. Regional political bodies were ineffective, and Gadaffi was the only one to make political decisions. It was an authoritarian police state without political parties which violated the legal rights of all those that opposed it. Opposition to the regime was kept low through fear. Responses to protests were violent, and prisoners faced torture and executions (Simons, 2003, pp.101-107). These measures ensured the regime’s hold on power for a long time, but also caused widespread resentment. Thirdly, in a country that traditionally valued a sober lifestyle, the Gadaffi children exhibited their Western luxuries to the whole population. This further aggravated resentment (Pargenter, 2012, p.211).
Fourthly, the conflict in Libya is characterised by a strong regional division. Historically, the east has been the centre of resistance against Gadaffi. During the second half of the 1990s, Benghazi had been the centre of an Islamist uprising against the regime. According to Pargenter, Gadaffi’s response was to keep the East in a ‘constant state of underdevelopment’, in order to make it feel what it means to challenge the regime (2012, pp.170-1). The Gadaffi policies towards the East were important in forming the necessary resentment for a prolonged rebellion. In 2001, 76% of the citizens in Benghazi felt alienated from the political process and sought change (Warshel, 2012, p.735). It was the East that finally rose up against the regime, with Benghazi as its most important city.
Fifthly, Gadaffi had long exploited the tribal differences in Libya. Initially, Gadaffi played out the different tribes against each other, with three tribes as the main pillars under his regime. After an attempted coup by the Warfalla tribe in 1993, the Libyan leadership consisted entirely of members of the Gadaffa, the leader’s own tribe (Martinez, 2007, p.99). This way Gadaffi ensured their loyalty to the regime. As a consequence the rest of the population had no perspective at representation or improving its position and was kept on a leash through coercion. It is argued that tribal loyalties shaped allegiances during the revolution, although they were less important than the regional division (Lacher, 2011, pp.144-5).
Each of these factors can be argued to have played a role in inciting resistance against Gadaffi’s regime. As a whole, they led to the image of a Gadaffi regime that was illegitimate and, certainly for those in the East and from outside the Gadaffa tribe, as a regime that caused a lot of suffering. Based on the narrative of the protests, these are the concerns that were crucial in motivating people to take up violent rebellion. However, as with greed-based motivations, we need more detailed research into the motivation of individuals to be certain about which factors were more prominent in driving their behaviour.
The Role of Opportunity
Having established that grievances provide a more likely explanation as a motivation for conflict in Libya than greed, are greed and grievance a useful distinction to explain rebellion? According to Berdal (2005, p.689): ‘the conceptual distinction between greed and grievance is not in fact terribly useful, either in explaining the motivation or persistence of wars’ (italics in original). He argues that, in recent works, scholars have moved to regard the opportunity for violence as the more relevant object of study under the ‘greed’ category. In response, Collier modified his greed thesis to focus on the feasibility of rebellion (Keen, 2012, p.757). In the next section, I will consider the opportunity for rebellion in Libya.
For this, it can be helpful to look at rebellion as a collective action problem. Lichbach (1994) calls this the ‘Rebel’s Dilemma’: the problem that people generally do not participate in protests. In their choice whether or not protest, a rational actor would weigh the costs and benefits of protesting. People who take the decision to take to the street risk punishment from the regime, for example in the form of violence or imprisonment. On the other hand, the decision is determined by the chance that the protest succeeds to overthrow the regime. A more advanced model of these choices can be found in Heckathorn (1988). Solving the Rebel’s Dilemma is a dynamic process. The government tries to prevent the rebels from succeeding in overcoming the Rebel’s Dilemma, whereas the rebels, to the extent that they are organised, try to find a strategy to overcome the collective action problem.
In the case of Libya before 2011, the Gadaffi government was very consistent in its approach to prevent protests from spreading. ‘The state apparatus [Gadaffi] created persisted for so long not through legitimate support, but because the regime simply [was not, or could not be] opposed’ (Warshel, 2012, p.734). In such a situation, fear for repression can become a more important concern than countering grievances. As long as the regime has the organisational capacity to keep rebels in check, and the protesters lack strength and cohesion, a leader will manage to stay in power (Potocki, 2011, p.57). In 2011, the protests in Libya finally gained momentum. In that regard, a possible explanation is the unique regional context: the early Arab Spring protests showed that the autocratic regimes were not all-powerful in cracking down on dissidents (Kneissl, 2011), lowering the perceived opportunity costs for protesters.
Beyond ‘Greed and Grievance’
The case of Libya seems to suggest that even though grievances played an important role as a motivation for rebellion, the specific circumstances of 2011 were crucial in allowing the outbreak of civil war. It was the simultaneous existence of grievances and the right set of conditions for an opportunity for rebellion that both made civil war necessary, and allowed it to take place. In other words, these conditions allowed the Rebel’s Dilemma to be overcome. Collier focuses his more recent writings on economic opportunity (Keen, 2012, p.757), where people rebel because they expect to gain a higher income as a result. However, the case of Libya suggests that we should look at a concept of opportunity that takes non-economic factors into account. In Libya the first of these factors is the behaviour of the Gadaffi government, reducing its internal legitimacy and isolating itself from outside support through violent actions and rhetoric (Whitaker, 2011). Additionally, in contrast to what Collier et al. argue it was the increase in education that played a role in allowing the revolution to take flight. People with high levels of education are generally more likely to get politically involved (Champante and Chor, 2012, p.174). This, amongst others, was likely to play a role in allowing the rapid organisation of the opposition after the start of the protests (Pargenter, 2012).
Grievances of the Libyan population have long-established roots, but it was not until 2011 that they finally found an effective way to express those grievances. The sequence of events seems to suggest that violent rebellion in Libya was strongly grievance-induced. In general, it can be said, that the distinction between greed and grievance only provides a limited explanation of the outbreak of civil wars. It is useful to provide a categorisation of different potential motivations. However, as previous case studies have already shown, greed and grievance factors often interact and the distinction thus falsely assumes that these are two distinct analytical categories (Berdal, 2005, p.691). The more important question is to what extent the grievances are perceived as fundamental enough for citizens to rebel and whether they perceive that a rebellion is viable. Only by mapping the individual motivations of Libyan rebels it becomes possible to determine which motivation was more crucial in their decision to fight. In general, in order to fully grasp the causes of the civil war, it would be helpful to focus on research that attempts to determine individual rebels’ motivations for joining the struggle.
All in all, while grievances seemed to play an important role as a motivation in Libya, ‘greed’ does not provide a convincing explanation. Opportunity would be a more appropriate phrase, as the economic motivations do not come forward out of greed but rather out of the feasibility of the revolution. These economic opportunities also require several non-economic conditions that make protests possible. Lastly, it would be most helpful to study the interplay of opportunity and grievances: where the two coincide, the chances of civil war breaking out are the highest.
Bibliography
Berdal, Mats, 2005. Beyond Greed and Grievance – and not too soon: A Review Essay. Review of International Studies . 31(4), pp. 687-698.
CIA, 2012. The World Factbook: Libya . [online] Available at: < https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ly.html > [Accessed 24 November 2012].
Campante, Filipe R. and Chor, Davin, 2012. Why was the Arab World Poised for Revolution? Schooling, Economic Opportunities, and the Arab Spring. Journal of Economic Perspectives , 26(2), pp. 167-188.
Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke, 2000. Greed and Grievance in Civil War. World Bank Policy Research Paper 2355. Washington DC: World Bank.
Collier, Paul, Hoeffler, Anke and Rohner, Dominic, 2009. Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War. Oxford Economics Paper . 61(1), pp. 1-27.
Cramer, C., 2002. Homo Economicus Goes to War: Methodological Individualism, Rational Choice and the Political Economy of War. World Development , 30(11), pp. 1845-1864.
England, Andrew and Blas, Javier, 2011. Libya rebels fight to keep oil lifeline open. Financial Times, [online] 7 April. Available at: < http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/711c6cd6-6146-11e0-ab25-00144feab49a.html#axzz2DBL7WWlJ > [Accessed 24 November 2012].
Florea, Adrian, 2012. Where Do We Go from Here?: Conceptual, Theoretical, and Methodological Gaps in the Large-N Civil War Research Program. International Studies Review , 14(1), pp. 78-98.
Heckathorn, Douglas D., 1988. Collective Sanctions and the Creation of Prisoner’s Dilemma Norms. American Journal of Sociology , 94(3), pp. 535-562.
Kabbani, Nader and Ekta Kothari, 2005. Youth Employment in the MENA Region: A Situational Assessment. World Bank Social Protection Working Paper . [online] Available at: < http://siteresources.worldbank.org/SOCIALPROTECTION/Resources/SP-Discussion-papers/Labor-Market-DP/0534web.pdf > [Accessed 2 December 2012].
Keen, David, 2000. Incentives and Disincentives for Violence. In: Berdal, Mats and Malone, David, eds. 2000. Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars . Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Keen, David, 2012. Greed and Grievance in Civil War. International Affairs, 88(4), pp. 757-777.
Kneissl, Karin, 2011. Elements for a Scientific Analysis of the Arab Revolutions in Spring 2011. AAS Working Papers in Social Anthropology . [online] < http://hw3.arz.oeaw.ac.at/0xc1aa500d_0x00290d58.pdf > [Accessed 2 December 2012].
Lacher, Wolfram, 2011. Families, Tribes and Cities in the Libyan Revolution. Middle East Policy, 18(4), pp. 140-154.
Lichbach, Mark I., 1994. Rethinking Rationality and Rebellion: Theories of Collective Action and Problems of Collective Dissent. Rationality and Society , 6(1), pp. 8-39.
Martinez, Luis, 2007. The Libyan Paradox . Translated from French by John King. London: Hurst and Company.
Miller, Morris, 2000. Poverty as a Cause of Wars? Interdisciplinary Science Review , 25(4), pp. 273-297.
Nathan, Laurie, 2005. The Frightful Inadequacy of Most of the Statistics: A Critique of Collier and Hoeffler on Causes of Civil War . Crisis States Research Centre LSE, Discussion Paper no.11 . [online] Available at: <eprints.lse.ac.uk/28337/1/dp11.pdf> [Accessed 23 November 2012].
Pargeter, Alison, 2012. Libya: The Rise and Fall of Qaddafi . New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Potocki, Rodger, 2011. Belarus: A Tale of Two Elections. Journal of Democracy, 22(3), pp. 49-63.
Simons, Geoff, 2003. Libya and the West: From Independence to Lockerbie . Oxford: Centre for Libyan Studies.
Stewart, Frances, 2002. Horizontal Inequalities as a Source of Conflict. In: Fen Osler Hampson and David Malone, eds. 2002. From Reaction to Conflict Prevention: Opportunities for the UN System. Boulder: Lynne Rienner, pp. 105-138.
Tignor, Robert L., 2011. Can a New Generation Bring about Regime Change? International Journal of Middle Eastern Studies , 43(3), p. 384.
Vandewalle, Dirk, 2012a. A History of Modern Libya . 2 nd ed. Cambridge: University Press.
Vandewalle, Dirk, 2012b. Dirk Vandewalle on Libya After Gadaffi . Available at: < http://www.youtube.com/watch?feature=player_embedded&v=uZ93s41at_8 > [Accessed 24 November 2012].
Warshel, Yael, 2012. Political alienation in Libya: assessing citizens’ political attitude and behaviour. Journal of North African Studies , 17(4), pp. 734-737.
Whitaker, Brian, 2011. Gaddafi’s Fall Unlikely to Alarm Arab Leaders. Guardian. [online] Available at: < http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2011/aug/22/muammar-gaddafi-arab-leaders-analysis > [Accessed 9 February 2013].
— Written by: Wim van Doorn Written at: King’s College London Written for: Mats Berdal Date written: December 2012
Further Reading on E-International Relations
- The (Un)intended Effects of the United Nations on the Libyan Civil War Oil Economy
- The Angolan Civil War: Conflict Economics or the Divine Right of Kings?
- The Mobilisation of Sectarian Identities in the Syrian Civil War
- Female Combatants: Same goals, different motivations?
- Were ‘Ancient Hatreds’ the Primary Cause of the Yugoslavian Civil War ?
- Understanding Power in Counterinsurgency: A Case Study of the Soviet-Afghanistan War
Please Consider Donating
Before you download your free e-book, please consider donating to support open access publishing.
E-IR is an independent non-profit publisher run by an all volunteer team. Your donations allow us to invest in new open access titles and pay our bandwidth bills to ensure we keep our existing titles free to view. Any amount, in any currency, is appreciated. Many thanks!
Donations are voluntary and not required to download the e-book - your link to download is below.


African Security
Greed and civil war in post–cold war africa: revisiting the greed theory of civil war.
- Download citation
- https://doi.org/10.1080/19392206.2011.629552

Original Articles
- Full Article
- Figures & data
- Reprints & Permissions
- Get access /doi/full/10.1080/19392206.2011.629552?needAccess=true
This article revisits the so-called “greed theory” (or “greed hypothesis”) of civil war, which is one of the most influential theories of civil war, adopted in recent years by many scholars and policymakers around the world. Applying the greed theory to the sixteen cases of African countries involved in civil wars during the post–Cold War period (1989–2006), the article assesses how well these cases fit into the theory's argument and policy recommendations. As a result, the article argues that the greed theory does not provide a good explanation of the outbreak of civil wars in these countries, nor does it provide good policy recommendations that would help resolve and prevent most of these civil wars. Ultimately, recognizing the deficiencies of the quantitative and deductive research methods used by the authors of the greed theory, the article makes the argument that the alternatives to this theory should be based on qualitative and inductive research methods that would take into consideration not only the existence of different levels of analysis of civil wars but also their dynamic nature.
- post–Cold War
- greed theory
- conflict analysis
1. Nils Petter Gleditsch, Peter Wallensteen, Mikael Eriksson, Margareta Sollenberg, and Havard Strand, “Armed Conflict 1946–2001: A New Dataset,” Journal of Peace Research 39, no. 5 (2002): 615–37; Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP) and International Peace Research Institute (PRIO), “ UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset, Version 4–2007, 1946–2006 ,” 2007, www.pcr.uu.se/publications/UCDP_pub/Main_Conflict_Table_19467–2006.xls .
2. Conventionally, an armed conflict is defined as “a contested incompatibility that concerns government and/or territory where the use of armed force between two parties, of which at least one is the government of a state, results in at least 25 battle-related deaths” (Uppsala Conflict Data Program and International Peace Research Institute, UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset Codebook , 4). The difference between a minor armed conflict and a war is based on the number of battle-related deaths: whereas a minor armed conflict would cause “between 25 and 999 battle-related deaths in a given year,” a full scale war would result in “at least 1,000 battle-related deaths in a given year” (Uppsala Conflict Data Program and International Peace Research Institute, UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset Codebook , 10).
3. Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 2355, 2000, World Bank, www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2000/06/17/000094946_00060205420011/Rendered/PDF/multi_page.pdf , accessed July 22, 2008; Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” Oxford Economic Papers 56, no. 4 (2004): 563.
4. Morten Boas and Kevin Dunn, “Introduction,” in African Guerrillas: Raging Against the Machine , ed. Morten Boas and Kevin Dunn (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2007), 1–8.
5. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2000; Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2004.
6. Susan Rice, Corinne Graff, and Janet Lewis, Poverty and Civil War: What Policymakers Need to Know , The Brookings Institution, December 2006, www.brookings.edu/views/papers/rice/poverty_civilwar.pdf , accessed June 29, 2008; Simeon Djankov and Marta Reynal-Querol, “The Causes of Civil War,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. WPS 4254, June 2007, http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2007/06/15/000016406_20070615144341/Rendered/PDF/wps4254.pdf , accessed July 16, 2008.
7. See the policy recommendations drawn from the greed theory and the United Nations General Assembly Resolution A/RES/62/11, 62 session, agenda item 13, “The Role of Diamonds in Fuelling Conflict,” December 18, 2007, http://daccessdds.un.org/doc/UNDOC/GEN/N07/464/43/PDF/N0746443.pdf?OpenElement , accessed July 31, 2008.
8. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2004.
9. Ibid., 564. Collier and Hoeffler are referring here to Herschel I. Grossman, “A General Equilibrium Model of Insurrections,” American Economic Review 81 (1991): 912–921; Herschel I. Grossman, “Kleptocracy and Revolutions,” Oxford Economic Papers 51 (1999): 267–283.
10. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2004, 574.
11. Ibid., 274–275.
12. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2000 (emphasis added).
13. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2004 (emphasis added).
14. Ibid.; James D. Fearon, “Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 4 (August 2005): 483–507; Michael Nest, Francois Grignon, and Emizet Kisangani, The Democratic Republic of Congo: Economic Dimensions of War and Peace (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2006).
15. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2004, 588.
16. Paul Collier, Anke Hoeffler, and Dominic Rohner, “Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War,” Center of the Study of African Economics Working Paper, May 2008, http://users.ox.ac.uk/~econpco/research/conflict.htm , accessed December 28, 2009.
17. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2000.
18. Kimberley Process, homepage, www.kimberleyprocess.com.
19. The United Nations General Assembly Resolution A/RES/62/11.
21. Collier, Hoeffler, and Rohner, “Beyond Greed and Grievance,” 17.
22. Uppsala Conflict Data Program and International Peace Research Institute, UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset.
23. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” (2004); James D. Fearon, “Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 4 (August 2005): 483–507; Michael Nest, Francois Grignon, and Emizet Kisangani, The Democratic Republic of Congo: Economic Dimensions of War and Peace (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2006).
24. Nest, Grignon, and Kisangani, The Democratic Republic of Congo .
25. Ibid., 11.
26. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database , 2008, www.ucdp.uu.se/database , accessed November 15, 2009.
28. Nest, Grignon, and Kisangani, The Democratic Republic of Congo, 129.
29. Collier and Hoeffler, “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” 2000.
30. Nicholas Sambanis, “Using Case Studies to Expand the Theory of Civil War,” Perspectives on Politics 2, no. 2 (June 2004): 259–79; James D. Fearon and David D. Laitin, “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War,” American Political Science Review 97, no. 1 (2003): 75–90; Morten Boas and Kevin Dunn, “Introduction,” in African Guerrillas: Raging Against the Machine , eds. Morten Boas and Kevin Dunn (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2007), 1–8.
31. Nicholas Sambanis, “Using Case Studies to Expand the Theory of Civil War,” Perspectives on Politics 2, no. 2 (June 2004): 259–279.
32. Boas and Dunn, “Introduction.”
33. Michael Lund, Preventing Violent Conflicts: A Strategy for Preventive Diplomacy (Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace, 1996); Michael Brecher and Jonathan Wilkenfeld, A Study of Crisis (Michigan: The University Press of Michigan, 1997); Paul Wehr, Conflict Regulation (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1979); Dennis J. D. Sandole, “A Comprehensive Mapping of Conflict and Conflict Resolution: A Three Pillar Approach,” http://www.gmu.edu/programs/icar/pcs/sandole.htm , May 9, 2011.
34. Lund, Preventing Violent Conflicts .
35. Wehr, Conflict Regulation ; Sandole, “A Comprehensive Mapping of Conflict and Conflict Resolution.”
36. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database .
38. Ibid.; Luis Martinez, The Algerian Civil War, 1990–1998 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1998).
39. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database .
41. Beverly Milton-Edwards, Islamic Fundamentalism Since 1945 (Making of the Contemporary World) (New York: Routledge, 2005); Oliver Roy, The Failure of Political Islam (London, UK: I B Tauris & Co., 1994).
42. William Reno, “Liberia: The LURDs of the New Church,” in African Guerrillas: Raging Against the Machine , ed. Morten Boas and Kevin Dunn (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2007), 69–80; Stephen Ellis, The Mask of Anarchy: The Destruction of Liberia and the Religious Dimension of an African Civil War (New York: New York University Press, 2007); Jonathan Stack, Liberia: An Uncivil War (California Newsreel, 2004), 102 minutes; Reed Kramer, “Liberia: A Casualty of the Cold War's End,” AllAfrica.com, July 1, 1995, http://allafrica.com/stories/200101090216.html , accessed August 23, 2008.
43. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database .
44. Wenche Hauge, “When Peace Prevails: The Management of Political Crisis in Ecuador, Madagascar, Tunisia and Venezuela,” Alternatives: Global, Local, Political 35, no. 4 (2010): 469–493; Wehr, Conflict Regulation ; Sandole, “A Comprehensive Mapping of Conflict and Conflict Resolution.”
45. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database ; Martinez, The Algerian Civil War.
46. Uppsala Conflict Data Program, UCDP Database .
Reprints and Corporate Permissions
Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?
To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:
Academic Permissions
Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:
If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form . For more information, please visit our Permissions help page .
- More Share Options
Related research
People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.
Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.
Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations. Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.
- People also read
- Recommended articles
Your download is now in progress and you may close this window
- Choose new content alerts to be informed about new research of interest to you
- Easy remote access to your institution's subscriptions on any device, from any location
- Save your searches and schedule alerts to send you new results
- Export your search results into a .csv file to support your research
Login or register to access this feature
Register now or learn more

IMAGES
VIDEO
COMMENTS
An action research paper documents a “cycle of inquiry,” in which the writer evaluates a problem and develops a strategy of reform. Educators and educational administrators typically use this writing format to foster continual improvement i...
To make an acknowledgement in a research paper, a writer should express thanks by using the full or professional names of the people being thanked and should specify exactly how the people being acknowledged helped.
Writing a research paper is a bit more difficult that a standard high school essay. You need to site sources, use academic data and show scientific examples. Before beginning, you’ll need guidelines for how to write a research paper.
Policy Research Working Paper;No. 2355. World Bank, Washington, DC. © World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/18853 License: CC BY 3.0
https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-2355 ... This paper - a product of the Development Research Group - is part of a larger effort in the
Collier, Paul & Hoeffler, Anke, 2000. "Greed and grievance in civil war," Policy Research Working Paper Series 2355, The World Bank. Handle: RePEc:wbk:wbrwps:
POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER. 2355. Greed and Grievance. Of the 27 major armed conflicts that occurred in in Civil W ar. 1999, all but two took place.
Working Paper 2355, Washington, D.C..
Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2000) Greed and. Grievance in Civil War, World Bank Policy Research. Working Paper 2355, Washington DC: World Bank.
In their original paper, Collier and Hoeffler use a number of 1.000 deaths per year as the baseline for 'civil war' (2000, p.4). However, other
2355, 2000, World Bank, ... Simeon Djankov and Marta Reynal-Querol, “The Causes of Civil War,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no.
American Political Science Review 94 (4): 779-801.
Bank, Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 2355.
Africa's growth tragedy: Policies and ethnic divisions.